Wajibu logo

A JOURNAL OF SOCIAL & RELIGIOUS CONCERN

Volume 15 No. 2 (2000)

Economics as if people mattered

|
CONTENTS | AFRICANEWS HOMEPAGE |

Relationships as building blocks for economics

by Peter Kimuyu

Introduction
As a social science, economics seeks to explain how people meet their many competing needs and wants from limited resources. This process is viewed as one of maximising personal satisfaction within the confines of a resource constraint. An important assumption in understanding this process is that people are self-interested and preoccupied with personal satisfaction. Are good relationships important for self-interested individuals? Do relationships have any economic value?

It has been observed that good filial relationships are not only healthy for parents and children but often spur the drive for achievement. Good marital and family relationships generates synergy that uniquely brings out productive potential and creativity bound up in individual members of a family. One evidence of good family relationship is where members of a family appreciate, encourage, and support each other. It is from such families that the motivation for achievement is nurtured.

Recent research shows that in work places where the owners, management and work force relate warmly, productivity is usually high. There are of course many measures of good relationships in a work situation, including disparities in incomes, the extent of diffusion of ownership, and the degree to which corporate dreams trickle down. A common vision, preoccupation with parity, intensive interactions and truthfulness are key pillars of a good relationship. Most of the positive side effects of good relationships arise from these pillars.

Relationships as Social Capital
Research views relationships as part of a society's social capital. This form of capital is increased when relationships change in a way that makes collective positive decision making more probable. It can be created, as when people who never saw eye to eye become friendly and able to pursue a common course. It can also be destroyed, such as when there is a general breakdown in relationships.

Social capital is part of a country's institutional foundation. Interactions between people generate norms that impose relational obligations. Acceptance of a norm leads to a personal commitment to be governed by the norm. Since norms tend to be general, persons who selectively accept a norm expect others to abide by it as well and the violators of the norm to be punished. When a larger proportion of a community shows commitment to a norm, such a norm tends to direct behaviour internally through respect and externally through fear.

How are social norms created? When people in a community have some incentive for indicating willingness to accept a practice, and when such acceptance increases general prosperity, people are unlikely to openly contest the practice. This consensus permits personalising of the norm by some members of the community who also pass it on to progeny. Thereafter, the new norm becomes part of a community's institutions.

Those who personalise a norm cooperate even when the payoff for cooperation is smaller than the payoff for opportunistic behaviour, an outcome referred to as principled conformity to a norm.2 On the other hand, individuals may fail to accept a norm but still cooperate when the objective payoff for cooperation is at least as high as the payoff for opportunistic behaviour. This latter outcome is referred to as an adventist conformity to a norm.

In other words, cooperation is influenced by forces resident in relational norms. Norms are standards of conduct which people believe they should follow to avoid sanctioning. They sustain patterns of behaviour when a society imposes sanctions against violators of such norms. In larger groups, interactions tend to be anonymous so that private sanctioning is of little benefit to the agents that punish. Where relational norms prompt people to take others into consideration, their very existence provides a framework for self-policing.

The tendency to cooperate is often greater for small groups since relational norms develop more easily in such groups In other words, voluntary cooperation-operation is more likely in smaller groups because repeated interactions result in fondness and lead to an establishment of codes of behaviour that assign positive value to compliance.

Relational Norms and Commerce
The emergence of a relational norm in a business community affects commercial behaviour in that private actors informally begin to punish violators of the norm. The type of cooperation-operation on which commerce thrives is enhanced in groups where different members share common traits.3 Social virtues such as trust, truth, acceptance and obligation are necessary for proper functioning of markets. When the marketing jurisdictions expand beyond the small group horizon, the efficacy of these virtues slowly disappears so that they have to be replaced by more formal mechanisms that sustain market exchanges.

Long-term, interpersonal relationships support time dependent exchanges, but only provide safeguards for capital flows of a particular kind. This is why, although trade and commerce can be found everywhere, industrialisation tends to be more restricted because it requires other forms of institutional protection. At any rate, relational norms form the bedrock on which transactions are founded.

In business networks, investment takes place among private individuals that have a lasting relationship. When private individuals are committed to such relationships, voluntary cooperation-operation becomes a side effect. But enduring relationships derive from friendships, kinship, religion or ethnicity, and substitute for state enforced laws. The groups around which an enduring relationship is structured develop strong ideologies that become instrumental in stabilising and enforcing relationships.

In situations where exchange is market intensive and the costs of doing business are high, institutions arise to minimise such costs. Such institutions emphasize either relationships or sharing of information through communities or networks.4 This relational contracting deters anti-social behaviour such as cheating, primarily because in choosing either to cheat or not to cheat, participants compare the short-term gains of such behaviour with the long-term losses and the costs of establishing a fresh relationship. An example here is trade credit which only flows towards enterprises that have invested in developing reputation with their suppliers.

Since people trust others they already know, trusting results from repeated success in exchange situations. The building of trust is time costly. Where business parties also share social activities such as funerals, weddings and religious meetings, socialisation becomes an important side effect of business. Potential exchange parties who socialise extensively and also experience more business contacts are more inclined to trade with one another as they can more easily find and screen each other.

Because members of an ethnic group tend to socialise among themselves, they tend to find common acquaintances among themselves and a referral system emerges that could lead to ethnically concentrated business networks. Family, religion and ethnicity play critical roles in initiating business networks but such networks are kept in place by the business itself. This is because commercial relationships are nurtured in business meetings.

Summary
Yes, relationships have considerable economic value since the quality of relationships among people has a significant influence on business pursuits and economic performance. But, unlike physical capital which is tangible and human capital which is somewhat less tangible, social capital is embodied in relationships and is therefore not easily tangible. It can either be a by-product of existing relationships or directly result from the emerging structure of social discourse. When social capital is a by-product, it is rooted in relations in which agents, parties and members are historically associated such as through ethnicity, family, religious or other ties. Networks may affect enterprise performance directly since they can be sources of information on technologies and markets. The technical information so obtained affects labour productivity, while information on markets makes enterprises more competitive.

Studies have revealed that in Kenya, rotating savings and credit schemes that draw participation from kinship and acquaintances are useful in mobilising funds. Some of the funds are used in either starting or expanding small businesses.5 Other studies have shown that persons who are part of business related support groups have better access to credit. For example, the Asian business community in Kenya enjoys considerable network externalities that improve the performance of Asian businesses.6 Of course, the side effects of networks are not always positive. Networks driven by gangsterism and those promoting tribalism have to be countered by legislation that promotes more progressive relational norms.

Notes
1. This paper draws from Kimuyu, P.K Institutions relevant to commerce and industry: moral norms, social capital, the state and the law." (IPAR discussion paper; PD No.21/2000). Nairobi: Institute of Policy Analysis and Research, 2000.
2. See Cooter, R.D. "Rules of state law and rule of law state: an economic analysis of the legal foundations of development (Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, 1996). Washington D.C. : World Bank, 1997.
3. See Baland, J.M., and J.P. Platteau. Halting degradation of natural resources: is there a role for rural communities? Rome: Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations, 1996.

4. Fafchamps, M. "Networks, communities and markets in Sub-Saharan Africa." Unpublished document, 1999.
5. Kimuyu, P.K. "Rotating savings and credit schemes in rural East Africa." World development, Vol. 27. no. 7 (1997).
6. Bigsten, A., P. Kimuyu and K. Lundvall. "Are informal enterprises really different?: evidence from small manufacturers in Kenya. (IPAR discussion paper; no. DP/020/99).



A JOURNAL OF SOCIAL AND RELIGIOUS CONCERN
Published Quarterly by DR. GERALD J. WANJOHI
Likoni Lane - P .O. Box 32440 - Nairobi - Kenya
Telephone: 712632


The Online publishing of WAJIBU is by Koinonia Media Centre.


GO TO WAJIBU HOMEPAGE